469 F2d 498 Stanley Works v. Federal Trade Commission

469 F.2d 498

1972 Trade Cases P 74,207

The STANLEY WORKS, Petitioner,
v.
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, Respondent.

No. 11, Docket 71-1742.

United States Court of Appeals,
Second Circuit.

Argued Sept. 20, 1972.
Decided Oct. 17, 1972.

John W. Douglas, Washington, D. C., for petitioner.

Alvin L. Berman, Washington, D. C., for respondent.

Before KAUFMAN, SMITH and MANSFIELD, Circuit Judges.

IRVING R. KAUFMAN, Circuit Judge:


Advertisement
view counter
1

This appeal presents important questions of antitrust law. The central issue is whether the August 1966 acquisition of Amerock Corporation by The Stanley Works violated Sec. 7 of the Clayton Act1 and Sec. 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act.2 The Federal Trade Commission held that it did and ordered divestiture.3 Stanley filed a petition asking this Court to review and set aside the Commission's order. See 15 U.S.C. Sec. 45(c). For the reasons given below, we believe the effect of the merger may be substantially to lessen actual competition in the national cabinet hardware market. Accordingly, we affirm the decision of the Commission and direct that its order be enforced.

I.

2

As always, resolution of a question of antitrust illegality requires us to describe the companies involved, analyze the product and geographic market in which they compete, and explore the structure of the industry affected by the merger, to the end that we may properly assess the probable effects of the merger on competition.

The Companies

3

Stanley is a Connecticut corporation engaged in the manufacture and sale of hand and power tools, hardware products, steel and steel strapping, with its principal place of business in New Britain, Connecticut. It is a large, multi-plant, multi-product concern with a history of expanding sales. In 1965, a year prior to the merger, Stanley's domestic sales were $123,000,000, an increase of $29,000,000 over its 1963 sales figures. For the period 1963-1965, its net earnings after taxes rose from $4,200,000 to $6,600,000, an advance of more than 57%. In 1965 Stanley's sales in the relevant product market4 were $814,000. It operated numerous production facilities, including plants located in California, Connecticut, Florida, New Jersey, North Carolina, Ohio, Tennessee, Vermont and Illinois.

4

Amerock was incorporated in 1928 and maintains its principal place of business in Rockford, Illinois. At the time of this merger, Amerock was engaged in the manufacture and sale of certain hardware products for use primarily in kitchens, in addition to a broad line of window, appliance, furniture and general household hardware products. Its domestic sales in 1963 totaled $23.8 million, and increased by 1965 to $29.4 million, an advance of more than 23%. Amerock's 1965 net earnings after taxes were $2.8 million, a gain of over 47% over its 1963 earnings figures. Amerock's 1965 sales in the relevant product market were in excess of $18,000,000.

The Industry

5

Since Section 7 of the Clayton Act forbids mergers between companies "in any line of commerce in any section of the country," when the merger may result in substantial lessening of competition, determination of the relevant product and geographic markets is of critical significance. See, e. g., Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 325, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 8 L.Ed.2d 510 (1962). Here the task of isolating the relevant markets has been made simpler for us, since Stanley and the Commission stipulated that within the general hardware industry, sales of cabinet hardware products in the Nation constitute the appropriate product and geographic markets. The parties agreed also that for purposes of this case, there are no relevant product or geographic submarkets. The Examiner and the Commission grounded their findings of fact on these stipulations; their findings are conclusive, if supported by substantial evidence. 15 U.S.C. Sec. 45(c).

6

The parties are agreed that cabinet hardware includes pulls, knobs, hinges, latches, catches and similar products, including drawer slides and shelving hardware, used principally in kitchen cabinets. The cabinet hardware market comprises two related lines, residential cabinet hardware and architectural, or institutional, cabinet hardware.5 Residential cabinet hardware is used in houses and apartments. At one time, residential cabinet hardware was made primarily of metal stampings and extrusions, and was essentially functional in nature, with simple lines and designs. In the years following World War II, as the American home began to reflect post-war economic affluence, consumer demand for more highly ornamented cabinet hardware designs increased, and the industry underwent a dramatic change. Manufacturers of residential cabinet hardware turned to a zinc die-casting process, and, as a result, products in this line were transformed into highly stylized, fashion-oriented items, which were offered in a wide variety of designs and finishes to complement the motifs of contemporary cabinet work. Virtually all residential knobs and pulls are now made by the diecasting method. This enables manufacturers to produce the intricate styles and designs demanded by consumers of residential cabinet hardware.

7

Architectural cabinet hardware is produced for use in institutional and commercial buildings, such as schools, recreational centers and office buildings. The marketing watchword of architectural cabinet hardware is embodied in the phrase, "form follows function;" products in this line must be more durable than residential cabinet hardware in order to withstand the heavier wear to which they are subject in an institutional or commercial setting. As a result, architectural cabinet hardware is rarely made by the die-cast method but is stamped out of bronze, brass, aluminum or steel. These metals are more durable than zinc die-cast material and also more expensive.

Market Shares


Advertisement
view counter
8

Cabinet hardware sales in the United States in 1965, a year prior to the merger, were between $76,000,000 and $80,000,000. The record discloses that in 1965, Stanley ranked as the tenth leading producer of cabinet hardware products with sales of $814,000, representing a market share of 1%. Amerock, the acquired company, ranked first as the seller of cabinet hardware products in the United States. Its 1965 sales exceeded $18,000,000, and the company controlled 22-24% of the market.6

9

The Commission upheld the Trial Examiner's finding that the cabinet hardware industry was concentrated. As the table in the margin indicates, the four leading firms in the industry accounted for total sales ranging from 49% to 51% of the market.7

II.

10

Our attention initially must focus on a threshold dispute between the parties. It is Stanley's contention that the rationale and critical findings of the Commission's decision indicate that the Stanley-Amerock merger was declared illegal solely on the ground that the merger eliminated potential competition in the cabinet hardware market. The Commission opposes this characterization of its decision and insists that elimination of both actual and potential competition triggered application of Clayton Sec. 7 to the merger. The Commission's position on appeal is that either ground for its decision adequately made out a violation of the Clayton Act in this case. The argument is of central importance because under the rule enunciated in SEC v. Chenery Corp., 318 U.S. 80, 92, 63 S.Ct. 454, 87 L.Ed. 626 (1943), we must find that the considerations urged on appeal in support of the Commission's order are tion was based, if we are to sustain the order.

11

Chenery instructs that "the orderly functioning of the process of review requires that the grounds upon which the administrative agency acted be clearly disclosed and adequately sustained." Chenery, supra, 318 U.S. at 94, 63 S.Ct. at 462. It is clear to us that the Commission's decision was dual pronged and that the Stanley-Amerock merger was invalidated on both actual and potential competition grounds. And in our view, the actual competition case was "clearly disclosed" within the meaning of Chenery.8

12

We do not develop a "new ground" for the Commission's holding, as the dissent mistakenly suggests, but find the actual competition case clearly underscored in the proceedings before the Examiner, and also in the opinion rendering the Commission's decision. The complaint charged that as a result of the merger "substantial actual and potential competition has been, or may be, eliminated." Stanley's clear perception that an actual competition theory had been litigated before the Trial Examiner is evident from its brief on appeal to the Commission which discussed the merits of the actual competition case at some length.9

13

To preserve the integrity both of judicial review and of agency procedures we must be persuaded not only that Stanley had notice of the actual competition theory, but that the Commission specifically adopted the actual competition case as a reason for its decision. Any doubts on that score, however, are convincingly dispelled by a careful reading of the Commission's opinion, which repeatedly relates the effect of the merger on actual competition.

14

The Commission adopted at the outset the Examiner's finding that "the merger between Stanley and Amerock led to increased concentration in the already concentrated cabinet hardware market as well as eliminating Amerock as the leading independent producer of cabinet hardware . . . ." Unmistakably this is the argot of an actual competition case.

15

Moreover, that portion of the Commission's opinion which discussed the competitive effects of the Amerock acquisition articulated the Commission's overall view of the case in language that indicates beyond doubt the mix of actual and potential competition theories underlying the Commission's decision. It was the Commission's view that the "case presents . . . a mingling of the effects which are traditionally cognizable under the discrete categories of actual and potential competition." After reviewing Stanley's role in the cabinet hardware market, the Commission characterized Stanley as both "an actual and potential competitor in the stipulated market." "Viewing the case in this light," the Commission concluded, "and within the general confines of the established analytical framework relating to actual and potential competition, we are convinced from the present record that the examiner was correct in concluding that the merger of Stanley and Amerock had significant anticompetitive consequences proscribed by Section 7 . ."

16

In addition, the Commission's opinion (footnote 12), establishes clearly that the elimination of actual competition was a ground on which the Commission's decision rested. Noting that the examiner had concluded that the cabinet hardware market was concentrated, the Commission cited two studies10 which bolstered that finding. The opinion sets forth the view shared by a number of scholars that "any horizontal acquisition involving a firm with more than 20% of the relevant market [Amerock's share was 22-24%] should be deemed illegal," and refers to authorities which support that view.11 Both sources, at the cited pages, clearly address themselves to cases in which mergers eliminated actual competition.

17

Finally, and most covincingly, the Commission emphasized the importance of closely scrutinizing mergers in markets that are already concentrated, relying on United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 83 S.Ct. 1715, 10 L.Ed.2d 915 (1963). The question in that case was whether a merger between Philadelphia National Bank and Girard Trust Corn Exchange Bank, the second and third largest commercial banks in the Philadelphia metropolitan area, violated Sec. 7 by lessening competition in the commercial banking business. The Court held that it did, and grounded its decision on the elimination of actual competition. The Commission clearly understood and considered the rationale of the case, and applied it to the Stanley-Amerock merger.

18

In light of the above, we would be remiss in our duty as a reviewing court if we abstained from considering the merits of the actual competition theory and remanded the case to the Commission, as Stanley urges us to do. The record contains ample evidence to enable this Court to assess the merits, and it is abundantly clear that the Commission relied on the actual competition theories, among others, in reaching its conclusion. Chenery does not predicate judicial review of an agency finding on the correctness of that finding, nor does it require an agency to crystallize its basis of decision into a single, rarefied reason. All that is required is that "[i]f the administrative action is to be tested by the basis upon which it purports to rest, that basis must be set forth with such clarity as to be understandable." SEC v. Chenery Corp. (Chenery II), 332 U.S. 194, 196, 67 S.Ct. 1575, 1577, 91 L.Ed. 1995 (1947). We believe the Commission's decision with respect to he actual competition case satisfies that test.

III.

19

Having reached the merits, we must decide whether the effect of the merger "may be substantially to lessen competition" in the cabinet hardware market. Mindful of the admonition that questions of antitrust law are not always "susceptible of a ready and precise answer", United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, supra, 374 U.S. at 362, 83 S.Ct. at 1741, we take as our starting point, and touchstone of analysis, that "[t]he dominant theme pervading congressional consideration of the 1950 amendments [to Sec. 7] was a fear of what was considered to be a rising tide of economic concentration in the American economy." Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 315, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 1518, 8 L.Ed.2d 510 (1962). And we recognize "that a keystone in the erection of a barrier to what Congress saw was the rising tide of economic concentration, was [Sec. 7's] provision of authority for arresting mergers at a time when the trend to a lessening of competition in a line of commerce was still in its incipiency. Congress saw the process of concentrtion in American business as a dynamic force; it sought to assure the Federal Trade Commission and the courts the power to brake this force at its outset and before it gathered momentum." Id. at 317-318, 82 S.Ct. at 1520.

20

Unlike the factual settings presented in Brown Shoe, supra, United States v. Von's Grocery, 384 U.S. 270, 86 S.Ct. 1478, 16 L.Ed.2d 555 (1960), and United States v. Pabst Brewing Co., 384 U.S. 546, 86 S.Ct. 1665, 16 L.Ed.2d 765 (1966), where an analysis of the relevant market structure revealed only a trend toward concentration, the Commission clearly found here that the relevant market was already concentrated. Stanley argues, however, that the failure to find a trend toward concentration takes this case out of the line of Brown, Von's and Pabst, decisions which held horizontal mergers between actual competitors invalid. But United States v. Continental Can, 378 U.S. 441, 84 S.Ct. 1738, 12 L.Ed. 2d 953 (1964), teaches that where a market is already concentrated any merger between market leaders is suspect. The court said:

21

[W]here there has been a "history of tendency toward concentration in the industry" tendencies toward further concentration "are to be curbed in their incipiency." Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S., at 345, 346, 82 S.Ct. [1502] at 1535. Where "concentration is already great, the importance of preventing even slight increases in concentration and so preserving the possibility of eventual deconcentration is correspondingly great." United States v. Philadedphia National Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 365, n. 42, 83 S.Ct. 1715, 1742 [10 L.Ed.2d 915]; United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, [377 U.S. 271, 84 S.Ct. 1283, 12 L.Ed.2d 314 (1964)]. United States v. Continental Can, supra, 378 U.S. at 461-462, 84 S.Ct. at 1749.12

22

We have indicated that the four leading firms in the cabinet hardware industry dominated 49-51% of the market. The Examiner and the Commission thought these figures reflected market concentration. We agree that the industry is sufficiently concentrated to invoke the proscriptive sanction of the Clayton Act under the circumstances of this case.13

23

The relevant literature strongly supports this view.14 To mention only one example, Kaysen and Turner describe a "tight oligopoly" as an industry in which eight firms or less supply 50% of the market, with the largest firms controlling 20% or more.15 Under their analysis, the cabinet hardware market falls well within the economic parameters which describe a concentrated market.

24

Most persuasive of all in our view, however, is the unanimity reached by the trial examiner and the Commission in holding this market concentrated. In view of the Commission's expertise in assessing the impact of business practices on economic market forces, we believe its judgment as to what type of market is concentrated for antitrust purposes is entitled to substantial weight.16

25

Upon its review of all the evidence, the Commission concluded that

26

. . . the very reasons leading Stanley to acquire Amerock are the same reasons which support the charge in this case that the merger will have significant anticompetitive effects. Stanley acquired Amerock precisely because it was the dominant company in the market . . . and because it believed that the acquisition would further entrench Amerock's already dominant position, while any other course designed to achieve Stanley's goals in the cabinet hardware market -internal expansion by Stanley or acquisition of a smaller company in the industry-would only stir up competition.

27

There was substantial evidence in the record to support that view. Among the evidence we find a Stanley Hardware Division task force report, prepared on June 10, 1964, as part of a study of possible new ventures for the Hardware Division, which concluded:

28

it is felt that a strong Stanley entry into parts of the cabinet hardware market via product development could be expected to accentuate industrywide declines in prices and profits. A strong properly oriented Stanley entry into the market via acquisition could, on the other hand, be designed to contribute to a reversal in the downward trend in prices and profits.

29

In the general hardware industry, in which most of Stanley's business was transacted, it was not only the leading firm, but a price leader as well. A longrange Stanley Hardware Division report, prepared in mid-1965, stated: "As the largest firm in the industry, the Hardware Division must continue to show leadership in the important area of pricing policy. As conditions warrant, we must continue to take the initiative and corresponding risks of being the first within the industry to raise prices and attempt to keep them at such higher levels." This policy undoubtedly presented a threat to the future competitive vitality of the industry, which had recently experienced price decreases.

30

In light of these disclosures, the Commission justifiably was apprehensive that the Stanley-Amerock merger, by increasing concentration at the top of the market, might have a "tipping effect" in the cabinet hardware industry, turning a concentrated market manifesting limited signs of price competition into a rigid, lifeless market tending toward even greater concentration and economic enervation. A market as delicately balanced as this, such that a merger between the first and tenth ranking firms threatens substantial anti-competitive consequences, is "concentrated" by any measure. Section 7's incipiency standard, which "requires not merely an appraisal of the immediate impact of the merger upon competition, but a prediction of its impact upon competitive conditions in the future",17 provides preventive as well as remedial therapy for an ailing industry; surely its salutary medicines need not be withheld until the diagnosis reads "terminal."

31

Stanley argues that foreclosure of a de minimis share of a market bars application of Sec. 7, and that the competitive overlap between Stanley and Amerock in this case was de minimis. Our dissenting brother has adopted this view, but has based his conclusion on an altogether erroneous analysis of market shares. After parsing the stipulated product market, he proceeds to treat residential cabinet hardware and institutional cabinet hardware as distinct lines of commerce, thereby ignoring the clear agreement between the parties that no product or geographic submarkets exist in the cabinet hardware industry. He then announces, virtually ex cathedra, that the degree of competitive overlap existing between Stanley and Amerock amounted to a mere .35% of the market. The dissent concludes that the percentage of the market affected by the merger is de minimis and, on that account, Stanley's acquisition of Amerock survives even the most critical antitrust scrutiny. In light of the stipulation, we regard the dissent's method of analysis as puzzling. It is also dangerous for it may have the effect of both dissuading litigants from agreeing upon facts and deterring agencies from acting on those agreed stipulations of fact. No amount of statistical legerdemain justifies disregarding the binding stipulation that controls this case, under which the relevant product market is defined as the entire cabinet hardware industry and Stanley's market share is agreed to as constituting 1% of total sales. The parties conceded those facts, the Examiner acted upon those facts, and the Commission based its decision on those facts. There may have been strategic litigation tradeoffs that led to the adoption of the stipulation; but we shall never know. Nor can we guess what posture this case would have assumed had there been no stipulation. What constellation of facts might have emerged, but for the stipulation, is wholly a matter of surmise, in which we may not permit ourselves to engage. Having agreed on a set of facts, the parties, and this Court, must be bound by them; we are not free to pick and choose at will. While we recognize that Sec. 7 can tolerate de minimis foreclosure, Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S., at 329, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 8 L.Ed.2d 510, we cannot agree that the competition eliminated by this merger was sufficiently insubstantial to purge it of illegality under the Clayton Act.

32

Although the market shares involved here do not precisely match market shares in any case cited to us by either Stanley or the Commission-rarely are two antitrust cases alike-we believe that the rationale underlying at least two Supreme Court decisions indicates that Stanley's 1% is not a de minimis share of the cabinet hardware market. Most persuasive is United States v. Pabst Brewing Co., 384 U.S. 546, 86 S.Ct. 1665, 16 L.Ed.2d 765 (1966), in which a merger between two companies engaged in the manufacture, sale and distribution of beer was held invalid under Sec. 7 because it eliminated competition in three markets, including the national market.18 In the national market, Pabst ranked tenth among the leading firms, with 3.02% of the market; Blatz, the acquired company, ranked eighteenth with 1.47%. The relevant product market, though tending toward concentration, was not nearly as solidified as the market in this case: in 1957, one year prior to the Pabst-Blatz merger, 10 companies controlled 45.06% of the market; in 1961, ten companies controlled 52.6% of the market. Even after taking into account the trend toward concentration, competition in the product market in Pabst appears robust in comparison to the cabinet hardware market, in which four firms control approximately 50% of the market. In view of this market concentration in the sale of cabinet hardware products, we cannot assume, as Judge Mansfield does, that a difference of less than one-half of one per cent-the difference between Blatz's 1.47% and Stanley's 1% market shares-is of decisive significance for a question of such controlling importance as whether 1% market control is, or is not, de minimis.

33

Stanley's rank in the industry also contributes to the conclusion that its 1% share of the market is not insubstantial. The Supreme Court noted in United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 377 U.S. 271, 84 S.Ct. 1283, 12 L.Ed.2d 314 (1964), that central to the underlying philosophy of Sec. 7, as amended, is the principle "that competition will be most vital 'when there are many sellers, none of which has any significant market share.' United States v. Philadephia National Bank, 374 U.S. at 363, 83 S.Ct. 1715, 10 L.Ed.2d 915." United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, supra, 377 U.S. at 280, 84 S.Ct. at 1289. But the greater the concentration in the market "the greater is the likelihood that parallel policies of mutual advantage, not competition, will emerge. That tendency may well be thwarted by the presence of small but significant competitors." Ibid.19 In Alcoa, the Court specially noted that no more than a dozen companies could account for as much as 1% of industry production and therefore Rome, ranking ninth with 1.3% of the market, was a substantial competitor.20 Stanley, like Rome, is a small but significant competitor in a market with few sellers. Based on the record in this case, only ten companies, of which Stanley was tenth, accounted for 1% or more of the cabinet hardware market. We cannot say, therefore, that under the circumstances involved here, Stanley's 1% share was insubstantial.21

34

Finally, we note that though a market may be concentrated, forces may operate so as to maintain some level of competition and thus preserve the possibility of eventual deconcentration. That is why the continued independence of companies with relatively small market shares is so crucial to the health and vitality of a market threatening to become oligopolistic.22 Not only was Stanley an active competitor in the cabinet hardware market at the time it acquired Amerock but the record indicates that Stanley would have been a more active competitor in the future, absent merger.23 For all the reasons set forth, it is clear to us that the elimination of competition resulting from the merger was substantial and not de minimis, within the meaning of Sec. 7's prohibitions.

35

We cannot conclude without observing that our dissenting brother incorrectly reads our opinion as announcing a rule of per se illegality for horizontal mergers. This is regrettable for nothing we decide today remotely hints at such a conclusion. The law is clear in its teaching that in an already concentrated industry with few sellers, in which the four leading companies dominate approximately 50% of the market, a merger involving the leading firm, controlling 22-24% of the market, with a firm like Stanley, would seriously threaten substantial anticompetitive consequences. This merger cannot survive in the face of the Clayton Act and its history. Accordingly, we affirm the Commission's order and direct its enforcement.24

MANSFIELD, Circuit Judge (dissenting):

36

I respectfully dissent for the reason that in my view the majority, which adopts a new ground (the horizontal impact of the Amerock-Stanley merger on actual competition) for upholding the Commission's decision (which was squarely bottomed on elimination of potential competition), has automatically applied an oversimplified quantitative "rule of thumb" instead of recognizing economic realities of the market. It ignores the fact that the actual competitive overlap between the two companies is less than 1/2 of 1% of the market, that there has been a complete absence (1) of any trend toward concentration in the industry, (2) of any parallel action by leading producers, or (3) of any appreciable enhancement in the market power of the merged enterprise as compared with that of its two components.

37

The court's decision, therefore, amounts to a holding that a horizontal merger is per se unlawful even where one party controls but an infinitesimally small percentage of the market and there is a complete absence of indicia indicating a possible anti-competitive impact. The effect is to repeal the principle that "foreclosure of a de minimis share of the market will not tend 'substantially to lessen competition"', Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 329, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 8 L.Ed.2d 510 (1962). Since the record further establishes, as the majority implicitly recognizes, that the merger cannot be upset on the ground adopted by the Commission, i. e., elimination of potential competition, I would reverse the Commission's decision.

38

I further believe that the majority decision is unfortunate for the reason that by adopting a new ground for affirmance it has indulged in post hoc rationalization of agency action, a course condemned by the Supreme Court as incompatible with the Supreme Court as incompatible with the functioning and integrity of judicial review. SEC v. Chenery Corp., 332 U.S. 194, 196-197, 67 S.Ct. 1575, 1760, 91 L.Ed. 1995 (1947); Burlington Truck Lines, Inc. v. United States, 371 U.S. 156, 168-169, 83 S.Ct. 239, 9 L.Ed.2d 207 (1962). The Hearing Examiner limited himself to a finding that the merger might lessen competition in the cabinet hardware market because of the elimination of Stanley as a potential competitior.1 Upon review his decision was summarized by the Commission as being based on this potential competition ground.2 After a lengthy discussion of the competitive effects of the Amerock acquisition the Commission concluded:

39

"Accordingly, we conclude that the fact of its entry by acquisition eliminated the substantial possibility that Stanley itself would become a significant competitor in the cabinet hardware market, with all of the increase in competitive vitality which Stanley's presence would have implied." (Appendix at 128).

40

Apparently recognizing the weakness of the case based upon elimination of potential competition the majority now turns to elimination of actual competition as a ground for affirmance. This substitution of a horizontal basis, not invoked by the Commission, constitutes a departure from well established principles of review.

41

It is true that in the course of its discussion the Commission alluded to the degree of concentration in the cabinet hardware market, citing some authorities which refer to horizontal acquisitions, and stating that "Stanley's acquisition did or could contribute to the degree of competition prohibited by the statute." However, it is apparent that these passing references were merely intended to buttress a decision focused entirely on potential competition. If the Hearing Examiner or the Commission had considered the merger unlawful because of the horizontal overlap between Amerock and Stanley, they would have so stated in plain language; only one sentence would have been required. They did not do so, undoubtedly because (as is shown below) the overlap was too miniscule and insignificant to warrant such a finding. Indeed the Commission said, "Thus, it is not the 1% increase in market share brought about by the Stanley-Amerock merger by itself which posits the anticompetitive aspect of this merger." Although the Commission referred to Stanley's actual competition as a fact to be considered, the real basis of its decision was its finding of foreclosure of potential competition.

Actual Competition

42

Even assuming that the Commission's decision permits our consideration of the horizontal impact of the merger, undisputed market facts demonstrate that the merger's effect on actual competition was entirely too diminutive to violate Sec. 7 of the Clayton Act. The majority concludes that since the cabinet hardware industry is concentrated, with four firms controlling 49-51% of the market, a merger of the first ranking firm, Amerock (23%), and the tenth ranking firm, Stanley (1%), though bordering on de minimis, may have a "tipping effect" in the industry, which might tend to lessen competition. In support of this conclusion it relies upon an isolated report by subordinate marketing personnel employed by Stanley, prepared on June 10, 1964, and invokes Supreme Court decisions outlawing mergers by giants of industry in the fields of beer, aluminum, containers, shoes and banking, where there was either a higher market concentration or a trend toward such concentration in the industry under review.3

43

At first blush this traditional approach seems reasonable enough, particularly since antitrust law, at least with respect to the legality of mergers, has been characterized by decisions based on differences in degree rather than upon sharp, crystallized lines. See United States v. Philadelphia Nation Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 362, 83 S.Ct. 1715, 10 L.Ed.2d 915 (1963). However, we are not here dealing with industrial giants threatening to gobble up lesser competitive fry but with modest participants in a relatively small industry. Unlike the cases relied upon by the majority, there is here a complete absence of any trend toward concentration. Although the industry is somewhat concentrated, other characteristics of the market, including the existence of a large number of strong and thriving competitors, demonstrate that the instant merger cannot have the possible anti-competitive impact attributed to it. As for the evidence relied on by the majority, it is undisputed that the Stanley task force report referred to by it was neither seen nor approved by Stanley's management. On the contrary, the possibility of entry by either acquisition or by internal expansion was thoroughly rejected. On this record, therefore, I fail to find substantial evidence that would adequately sustain the view that the merger posed actual anti-competitive consequences which might tend to lessen competition. On the contrary, undisputed evidence with respect to competitive realities of the relevant market, including an overlap of less than 1% between the merging parties, compels me to conclude that neither the actual nor the potential competitive effects of the merger are unlawful and it should therefore be upheld.

44

Product markets and market percentages, whether or not stipulated, are of significance in determining the probable effect of a merger on competition where they reflect actual competition between the parties. But to determine whether a merger forecloses actual competition, one looks to the actual competitive facts (the competitive overlap between the parties) within the given product market rather than halt at overall market percentages and look no further. This process does not, as the majority suggests, change the parties' stipulation as to the overall market, or create distinct lines of commerce or submarkets. It merely judges actual competitive effects according to economic realities within the stipulated market rather than ignore undisputed competitive facts of record.

45

Applying this standard the record is clear that in this case the stipulated overall market percentages, while useful for some purposes, do not reflect the actual competition, i. e., the competitive overlap, between the parties within the stipulated market. Undisputed facts with respect to the actual competition between Stanley and Amerock reveal, on the contrary, that the competitive overlap between them is far less than the 1% accepted by the majority and that the merger is thus governed by the accepted principle that "foreclosure of a de minimis share of the market will not tend 'substantially to lessen competition,"' Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 329, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 1526, 8 L.Ed.2d 510 (1962). The de minimis impact of the Stanley-Amerock merger is due mainly to three factors: (1) the differing types of business conducted by each of the two participants, which for the most part do not compete, (2) the differing channels of distribution used by each, which likewise do not substantially compete, and (3) the fact that size does not carry any competitive advantages in this industry, where small companies thrive and have increased in number.

46

To appreciate the diminutive effect of the merger under review, certain facts about the industry, in addition to those described by the majority, should be known. Cabinet hardware comes in two kinds, (1) Residential, which is used in both houses and apartments, and (2) Architectural (Institutional) which is used in commercial or institutional structures. Residential hardware is highly stylized. Its production requires die-casting machinery, which is used to fashion intricate ornamentation. Architectural cabinet hardware, on the other hand, is primarily functional in design. Since sturdiness and durability are paramount, it is generally stamped out of metal.

47

Residential cabinet hardware is the vastly more significant part of the cabinet hardware industry, accounting for approximately 90-95% of the $76-$80 million total market-or about $72 million. The architectural market constitutes the remaining 5-10%, or approximately $8 million.

48

Distribution of cabinet hardware moves through six channels:

49

(1) Full Line Wholesalers, which carry predominately residential cabinet hardware for sale to retail hardware and department stores and, to a lesser extent to local builders and contractors;

50

(2) Specialty Wholesalers, which specialize in either architectural or residential cabinet hardware and sell to lumberyards, retail hardware stores, cabinet shops, and to small companies which build and sell finished cabinets, including the attached hardware;

51

(3) National Accounts (e. g., Sears, Montgomery Ward, J. C. Penney), which purchase residential cabinet hardware directly from the manufacturer and distribute it through their own retail outlets;

52

(4) Original Equipment Manufacturers of Residential Cabinets (Residential OEM's), which sell finished kitchen and bathroom cabinets. These companies are larger and more likely to be automated than residential cabinet shops; they avoid the wholesaler by purchasing directly from the manufacturer;

53

(5) Original Equipment Manufacturers of Architectural Cabinets (Architectural OEM's) the analogue to Residential OEM's in the architectural market. They purchase the hardware directly from the manufacturer and in turn sell finished institutional cabinets primarily to contractors for institutional structures;

54

(6) Contract Hardware Distributors, which sell the whole range of architectural hardware to institutional builders, generally on a bid basis.

55

Residential cabinet hardware is distributed through Full Line Wholesalers, National Accounts, Specialty Wholesalers and Residential OEM's. The latter two are used to distribute 2/3 of all residential cabinet hardware. Architectural hardware, on the other hand, is distributed through Specialty Wholesalers, Architectural OEM's and Contract Hardware Distributors. Each channel is aimed at particular kinds of ultimate buyers. There is little inter-channel competition. Thus, the method of distribution is crucial and represents an important gauge by which to measure competitive impact.

56

Amerock is the largest firm in the industry with approximately 23% of the market in 1965, the year immediately preceding the merger. Its 1965 sales totalled $18,218,474, with all but approximately $200,000 derived from the residential market. In contrast, Stanley's 1965 sales in the cabinet hardware industry totalled $814,000 or only 1% of the cabinet hardware market. More crucial, however, is the fact that only $200,000 of this figure, was derived from the residential market; the remaining $614,000 stemmed from architectural cabinet hardware sales.

57

Even these low figures do not accurately reflect Stanley's minimal competitive impact. Stanley owned no die-casting machinery-a sine qua non for full scale activity in the residential market. Several of its attempts to expand its share of the residential market had failed, giving it a poor reputation with distributors of residential hardware (i. e., Full Line Wholesalers, National Accounts, Specialty Wholesalers, and Residential OEM's). In fact, Stanley's sales in the cabinet hardware market were on decline. Thus, within the boundaries of the cabinet hardware market, which mark the outer limits of the "area of effective competition" under review, Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 324, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 8 L.Ed. 2d 510 (1962) (quoting from United States v. E. I. Du Pont De Nemours & Co., 353 U.S. 586, 593, 77 S.Ct. 872, 1 L.Ed.2d 1057 (1957), Stanley was definitely not a significant competitive force.

58

To determine whether the joinder of the market shares held by Stanley and Amerock posed an anticompetitive threat one must look beyond wooden percentage figures to live economic realities in the market itself, including such indicia as "reasonable interchangeability of use or the cross-elasticity of demand between the product itself and substitutes for it . . . the product's peculiar characteristics and uses, unique production facilities, distinct customers, distinct prices, sensitivity to price changes, and specialized vendors." Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 325, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 1523, 8 L.Ed.2d 510 (1962).

59

Applying these practical criteria, the record is clear that the percentage of actual competitive overlap between Stanley and Amerock prior to the merger was far less than Stanley's 1% of the overall cabinet hardware market. Stanley's sales of residential cabinet hardware, $200,000 out of total residential cabinet hardware sales of approximately $70,000,000, amounted to about 1/4 of 1% of the residential market, which is de minimis by any standard. Moreover, when one takes into consideration the channels of distribution used by the two parties to the merger, as required by Brown Shoe's mandate to consider "distinct customers" and "specialized vendors," the level of competition between them further decreases. Of Stanley's $200,000 derived from residential cabinet hardware sales, $8,041 was distributed via a single National Account, with the remainder directed to hardware and lumber outlets, mostly through Full Line Wholesalers. In contrast, 2/3's of Amerock's residential sales were through OEM's and specialty Wholesalers, with 1/3 going to Full Line Wholesalers and National Accounts. Thus, while there was a $20,000 competitive overlap, Stanley afforded no competition to Amerock's major channels of distribution.

60

As for the vastly less important area of institutional sales, which comprise only 5% to 10% of the aggregate cabinet hardware market, Stanley's percentage share is concededly higher.4 However, its larger share is misleading. Examination of competition within the relevant channels of distribution reveals that while Amerock's sales of institutional hardware totalled $200,000 and Stanley's were $614,000 each sold through noncompeting channels of distribution except for an overlap of $84,000.5

61

In summary, the total actual comptition between Stanley and Amerock amounted to an overlap of only $284,000 ($200,000 of residential sales and $84,000 of institutional sales), or approximately. 35% of the market. Even if we disregard other relevant factors (discussed below) which militate against the likelihood of competition being diminished, the percentage of the market affected by the merger is simply too small. See, e. g., Tampa Electric Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 365 U.S. 320, 329-334, 81 S.Ct. 623, 5 L.Ed.2d 580 (1961) (under analogous language of Sec. 3 of the Clayton Act); American Smelting and Refining Co. v. Pennzoil United, Inc., 295 F.Supp. 149, 157 (D.Del.1969) (1% increase in concentrated industry reduced in significance because of the nature of industry); United States v. First National Bancorporation, Inc., 329 F.Supp. 1003, 1019 (D.Colo.1971), juris. noted, 407 U.S. 902, 92 S.Ct. 2431, 32 L.Ed.2d 679 (1972) (even 1.2% insubstantial).

62

Other indicia traditionally considered in determining the legality of a merger allegedly violative of Sec.7 of the Clayton Act confirm that the impact here was too minuscule to be of antitrust significance. For example, the instant merger completely lacks a factor found to be of controlling significance in most leading horizontal cases,6 i. e., an industry-wide trend toward concentration either before or after the merger. It is uncontested that Amerock's share of the market remained constant through the 1965-1968 period. Moreover, there is no evidence of any other mergers between manufacturers in the industry at any time prior to or since the Amerock-Stanley merger.

63

Competition in the cabinet hardware industry has been vigorous, due in no small measure to the fact that it is a business in which numerous small companies, which can cater effectively to frequently changing stylistic demands of a specialized market, thrive. Thus size offers no effective competitive advantages. The market structure, regardless whether it be characterized as a "loose" oligopoly, satisfies "Congress' desire to promote competition through the protection of viable, small, locally owned businesses", Brown Shoe, supra, 370 U.S. at 344, 82 S.Ct. at 1534. In 1965 the four (4) largest firms comprised approximately 50% of the market, and the nine (9) largest totalled 65%. However, smaller firms, operating within limited geographical areas, have continued to offer vigorous competition, often enjoying a lion's share of the business within their respective locales. In fact, during the period 1963-1968, the number of firms in the market actually increased to a total of 97.7 At the same time prices and profits remain low. Such modest price increases as have occurred have been attributable largely to inflation, and have been at a slower pace and lower rate than prices of other building products. There is no evidence of price leadership or price uniformity. Nor is there any showing that the merger might tend to maximize profits for the members of the so-called oligopoly.

64

The healthy competitive climate in the industry may also be attributed in part to other factors. Unlike other markets (e. g., Clorox, beer, containers, banking) advertising plays but a minor role in the sale of cabinet hardware. Hence, a large advertising budget that might be provided by a financially powerful entrant is superfluous. This unusual characteristic is due in part to the highly specialized, style-oriented nature of cabinet hardware and to the fact that before it reaches the consumer it has been incorporated into a cabinet which is usually sold to the consumer without reference to the brand identity of the hardware forming part of it. From the standpoint of the hardware manufacturer, the significant buyers are the different types of distributors described above, which are relatively few in number. In the dominant residential hardware market, where style is a vital competitive factor, the small manufacturer, offering aesthetically pleasing designs to distributors within a limited geographical area, can successfully compete without an enormous expenditure on consumer advertising that would be required to sell a homogeneous product purchased directly by the consuming public, such as Clorox.

65

Of further competitive significance is the fact that among the many successful smaller manufcturers in the cabinet hardware market, several possessed the resources to expand in size if they considered such a move to be economically advantageous. At least four were subsidiaries or divisions of large diversified companies with substantial capital.8 In addition, several leaders in the manufacture of decorative furniture hardware, with die-casting facilities capable of being used to make residential cabinet hardware virtually identical with that made by those already in the field, had entered the residential hardware market, and others stood at its edge.

66

In such a commercial milieu, marked by robust and energetic competition, it is not surprising to find that Stanley's prior attempts at full-scale entry into the residential hardware market, where over 90% of all cabinet hardware is sold, had proved a failure. Indeed its sales in the hardware industry generally were on the decline.

67

The decisions cited by the majority in support of its conclusion that the horizontal impact of the merger might substantially lessen competition are all clearly distinguishable in legally significant respects. To the extent that "substantial" lessening of competition is measurable in terms of gross dollar volume Stanley's $814,000 annual sales of cabinet hardware, which involved a competitive overlap of $284,000, stands like a tiny pigmy in sharp contrast to the huge overlaps of $750,000,000 in United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 331, 83 S.Ct. 1715, 10 L.Ed.2d 915 (1963); $79,000,000 in United States v. Continental Can Co., 378 U.S. 441, 450, 84 S.Ct. 1738, 12 L.Ed.2d 953 (1964); $84,000,000 in United States v. Von's Grocery Co., 384 U.S. 270, 297, 86 S.Ct. 1478, 16 L.Ed.2d 555 (1966); $2,200,000 in United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 377 U.S. 271, 84 S.Ct. 1283, 12 L.Ed.2d 314 (1964); and many millions of dollars in Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 8 L.Ed.2d 510 (1962); and in United States v. Pabst Brewing Co., 384 U.S. 546, 86 S.Ct. 1665, 16 L.Ed.2d 765 (1966), where the precise dollar volumes are not reported. Taking into account that the relevant market in the present case is the entire United States a holding that a $284,000 competitive overlap constiutes substantial lessening of competition in violation of Sec. 7 of the Clayton Act amounts to an unwarranted overkill, hardly the type of target Congress intended to reach.

68

A comparison of other relevant circumstances confirms the inapplicability to the present case of the "horizontal" decisions relied on by the majority, in each of which the market was tainted by anticompetitive forces not found here. In Brown Shoe, which involved a merger of Brown Shoe Co., the third largest seller of shoes in the United States, and Kinney, the eighth largest company by dollar volume, there had been a steady and long-continued trend toward concentration in the relevant markets, characterized by vertical acquisition by manufacturers of retail outlets, which then sold a greater share of the new parent's shoes than formerly, and by horizontal mergers of these integrated behemoths. Hand in hand there went an equally relentless decrease in the number of shoe-manufacturing plants. "Brown Shoe was found not only to have been a participant, but also a moving factor, in these industry trends." 370 U.S. at 302, 82 S.Ct. at 1511. In six cities the combined share of children's shoe sales by the merged companies, Brown Shoe Co. and Kinney, exceeded 40%, and in one city their combined share of women's shoe sales exceeded 57%, 370 U.S. at 343.

69

In Philadelphia National Bank, supra, the merger, which was between the second and third largest competitors in the market area, would have resulted in one bank controlling 34-36% of a market in which the four largest banks would control 77-78%. Here also there had been a market trend toward concentration, with the number of competitors plummeting and the merger participants repeatedly playing a major role in that trend. The Court observed that the number of commercial banks had declined from 108 in 1947 to 42 in 1962, with Philadelphia National Bank having acquired nine formerly independent banks and Girard, the other party to the merger, six.

70

In Continental Can Co., supra, the top two firms, of which Continental Can was one, controlled nearly 49% of the $3 billion market (combined metal-glass containers) and the top six firms controlled 70.1%. Continental had a history of growth by horizontal acquisitions, having acquired no less than 35 firms in various interrelated container markets since 1913. 378 U.S. at 445, 84 S.Ct. 1738. Lastly, the company acquired under the challenged merger, Hazel-Atlas, ranked sixth largest with 3.1% of the market and had competed vigorously against Continental Can, competition which would be eliminated by the merger.

71

Von's Grocery, supra, which involved the third and sixth ranking firms in the market, is another example of one more merger in an industry marked by a precipitous trend toward increasing concentration of ownership, in which the larger firms played an active role in the continuing acquisition process. Of these firms the present participants were two of the most aggressive, each having doubled in size during the ten years immediately preceding the merger under attack.

72

Another decision referred to by the majority, United States v. Pabst Brewing Co., 384 U.S. 546, 86 S.Ct. 166, 16 L.Ed.2d 765 (1966), also cannot fairly be relied upon as governing the present case. It involved the merger of two huge brewers, which competed against each other in 40 states, in "an industry marked by a steady trend toward economic concentration". 384 U.S. at 550, 86 S.Ct. at 1668. Furthermore, there had been a steady increase in the size of the industry leaders, with a corresponding decrease in the overall number of competitors. The total number of competitors selling beer had declined from 206 to 162 in the five-year period from 1957 to 1962. Once again a strong anti-competitive trend had to be curtailed in its incipiency.

73

Lastly, the majority's heavy reliance upon United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 377 U.S. 271, 84 S.Ct. 1283, 12 L.Ed.2d 314 (1964), amounts to a wooden-like acceptance of substantially similar market percentage figures without making an analysis of the market structure to determine the true significance of the figures. Although the acquisition by Alcoa, with 27.8% of the aluminum conductor market, of Rome, with 1.3%, appears at first flush to be superficially similar as the merger here under review, a glance at the market there reveals how vastly different it is from that here. Unlike the present case, the top two competitors, including Alcoa, the industry leader, controlled 50% of the market and nine firms controlled 95.5%, foreclosing all but a tiny fraction from other competitors. More important, there had been a rapid trend toward concentration. "The absorption of Rome by Alcoa was one of the five acquisitions by producers of primary aluminum since 1957. . . . These moves, and the threat they were thought to pose, were specifically identified as factors influencing Alcoa's 1959 decision to acquire Rome. . . . As a result of this series of mergers, there now remain only four nonintegrated fabricators of aluminum conductor whose individual shares of total industry production . . . amounted to more than 1%." 377 U.S. at 279, n. 6, 84 S.Ct. at 1288. Since Rome had been an aggressive competitor, it is not surprising to find a judicial willingness to curtail the predatory conduct of the industry's leader, a giant by almost any standard, in attempting to absorb it. No case has gone beyond Alcoa. In view of the disparity in market concentration and the insubstantiality of the competitive overlap between Stanley and Amerock, which amounts to less than 1/2 of 1% of the stipulated market, extension of Alcoa to the instant facts is unwarranted.

74

Thus, even assuming that more stringent rules may be applied to horizontal mergers, because of the greater probability of their having an anti-competitive effect, than that to vertical or conglomerate mergers, in this case, unlike those relied upon by the majority, we have undisputed "evidence clearly showing that the merger is not likely to have such anticompetitive effects." United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, supra, 374 U.S. at 321, 83 S.Ct. at 1718.

Potential Competition

75

Having concluded that the Commission's decision should not be affirmed on the ground adopted by the majority, i.e., that the horizontal aspects of the merger may tend substantially to lessen competition, there remains the question of whether it should nevertheless be sustained on the ground advanced by the Commission, i.e., that the merger might substantially lessen competition by eliminating Stanley as a potential significant competitor in the manufacture and sale of residential cabinet hardware in that Stanley might have expanded either internally or by "toehold" acquisition of a smaller manufacturer, and that the merger therefore had the effect of increasing barriers to entry, and of destroying Stanley's disciplining effect at the edge of the market.

76

Although the majority opinion purports not to reach the potential competition issue, it does not hesitate to denigrate the Commission's position in several respects.9 In these views I concur. It further appears that none of the grounds advanced by the Commission in support of its potential competition theory is supported by substantial evidence. Indeed, in reviewing the record we are confronted with a rather extraordinary infirmity, bordering upon a denial of due process. The Commission's case before the Hearing Examiner rested heavily upon the testimony of officials of two of Stanley's competitors, supported by documents from the files of Stanley and Amerock. The two witnesses testified over Stanley's objection that it had not been allowed the opportunity to complete relevant discovery that would be material in its cross-examination of them. Nevertheless their testimony was taken and Stanley was later refused the right to recall the witnesses for the purpose of crossexamining them with evidence that had been adduced through intervening discovery. The Examiner's decision relied heavily upon the testimony of the two witnesses, which he quoted at length. When the unfairness of this procedure was raised upon appeal to the Commission, it decided to treat the testimony of the Commission's witnesses as stricken rather than permit cross-examination, with the result that it relied solely upon documentary evidence. Undisputed facts of record demonstrate that this reliance on the documentary evidence was improper, especially in view of the inconclusiveness of its contents.

77

The linch-pin of the Commission's opinion is its conclusion that but for the merger it was reasonably probable that Stanley would have entered the residential cabinet hardware market by internal expansion. This finding was bottomed entirely upon a series of reports and studies prepared by subordinate staff marketing personnel in the Stanley organization, which considered the possibility of internal expansion substantially prior to Stanley's acquisition of Amerock. As is often the case in large organizations, including governmental agencies such as the Federal Trade Commission and the Department of Justice, subordinates who are not invested with any decision-making responsibility will sometimes make colorful statements that do not reflect the views of the management. Ever since the famous "charnel house" letters used in United States v. Hartford-Empire Co., 46 F.Supp. 541 (N.D.Ohio 1942), modified, 323 U.S. 386, 65 S.Ct. 373, 89 L.Ed. 322 (1945), and the "Treanor" letter in Aetna Portland Cement Institute v. FTC, 157 F.2d 533, 577 (7th Cir. 1946), reversed, 333 U.S. 683, 68 S.Ct. 793, 92 L.Ed. 1009 (1948), such gems have been seized upon as the darlings of the government investigator. Even in case where the contents have been unauthorized and indeed are directly contrary to management decisions, they are paraded as if they had been approved. That is the case here.

78

Out of scores of studies prepared by low-level members of the staff of Stanley's Hardware Division, some of whom did not even have decision-making authority within that division and none of whom had the power to determine whether or not Stanley should expand its residential cabinet hardware production or acquire a competitor, the Commission has culled a few juicy comments such as the suggestions that acquisition of another manufacturer "Would knock out a competitor" or enable it "To obtain a dominant role in the hardware market." The Commission has committed the error of repeatedly mischaracterizing these studies as "management documents," "management reports," and "decisions made by Stanley's management," ignoring the undisputed fact that the documents were, by and large, neither seen nor approved by Stanley's management and that the management made unequivocal decisions to the contrary, which post-dated the studies and predated its acquisition of Amerock.

79

Even if some weight is given to the studies of Stanley subordinates relied upon by the Commission, a careful review of all such reports (as distinguished from the few quoted from by the Commission) reveals beyond question that their overall thrust was to reject internal expansion into the residential market and to concentrate on Stanley's exising product line, which was devoted mainly to architectural hardware. Furthermore, when action was finally taken by those corporate officers responsible for determining the company's basic policies, the decision was to reject the views of subordinates who advocated expansion into the residential field and to adopt the view that the hardware Division should concentrate on improving its existing architectural hardware line. More specifically, although the so-called "task force report," dated June 10, 1964, upon which the Commission relies, made by a group of relatively how-level staff personnel in the Hardware Division, suggested that acquisition of two cabinet hardware manufacturers, Ajax or Jaybee, be considered, it explicitly urged that internal expansion be rejected as unprofitable. Thereupon the Department Managers of the hardware Division, albeit still a stratum below the decision-making level, rejected entry by either route (acquisition or internal expansion), taking the position that internal expansion in the residential hardware field was not justified after weighing the size of the investment that would be required against the losses or limited profit that could be anticipated.

80

July 10, 1964, was the first time when Stanley's management became involved in the review of the question whether the company should expand its cabinet hardware division, acquire a competitor, or take some other course. On that date the Department Managers of the Hardware Division advised D. W. Davis, Executive Vice President, of their conclusions and recommended that the Hardware Division limit itself to concentrating on development of an improved line of architectural hardware, for which diecasting equipment would not be needed. In the meantime independent management consultants, Stewart, Douglas & Associates, were retained to identify new product areas in which the Hardware Division might expand. On December 23, 1964, it rendered its "think-tank" report which reinforced the conclusions of the Hardware Division by recommending against product expansion.

81

Armed with the foregoing reports and recommendations Davis held a meeting on January 8, 1965, with the various Managers of the Hardware Division, at which the final basic policy decision was reached that instead of expanding in the cabinet hardware field Stanley would concentrate on improving its existing product lines and maximizing sales and profits from those lines. Toward that objective responsibility for cabinet hardware was transferred to the Manager responsible for Contract (architectural) Products.

82

Despite overwhelming proof to the contrary the Commission, apparently proceeding on the erroneous assumption that the burden was on Stanley rather than on Commission counsel, see United States v. Penn-Olin Chemical Co., 246 F.Supp. 917, 919 (D.Del.1965), aff'd by an equally divided court, 389 U.S. 308, 88 S.Ct. 502, 19 L.Ed.2d 545 (1967), concluded, notwithstanding Stanley's unequivocal rejection of acquisition or expansion, that "[t]here is no persuasive indication in the record that respondent irrevocably adandoned either of these alternatives [acquisition of a competitor or internal expansion into resident hardware] in January of 1965." (Appendix at 126.) This crucial finding, unsupported by any substantial evidence, reflects administrative zeal which, while generally desirable, was misdirected in the present case. In a belated effort to support it with record proof, Commission counsel point to some rather euphemistic generalities in the Hardware Division's Long Range Plan, dated June 17, 1965, and in accompanying working papers, to the effect that during the latter part of the next five years the Division would "give increasing attention to the residential market." These statements by lesser personnel, however, are a far cry from reversal or modification of the final decision taken by Stanley's management on January 8, 1965. It was against this background that executives of Amerock in October, 1965, approached Stanley's Executive Vice President regarding the possibility of a merger. Faced with "a whole new ball game" Stanley for the first time reconsidered its earlier decision and finally decided in favor of the newly proposed merger.

83

Viewed in the light of Stanley's January 8, 1965 decision, it is clear that there is not substantial evidence to support the Commission's conclusion that but for the merger Stanley was a "reasonably probable" entrant into the residential hardware market. The Commission's evidence is far less persuasive than that in Penn-Olin, supra, where the district court concluded on remand that despite Olin's staff reports recommending entry

84

"The government has failed to sustain its burden of establishing by a preponderance of the evidence that . . there would have been a reasonable probability that Olin would have constructed a chlorate plant in the Southeast." United States v. Penn-Olin Chemical Co., 246 F.Supp. 917, 928 (D.Del.1965), aff'd by an equally divided court, 389 U.S. 308, 88 S.Ct. 502, 19 L.Ed.2d 545 (1967).

85

The Commission next asserts that the elimination of Stanley as a potential competitor may have substantially reduced competition by removing it as a disciplining force on the edge of the market. To exercise such an effect a minimum requirement is that "the merging firm at the edge of the market must be recognized by those in the market as the most likely entrant or one of a very few likely entrants. . . ." Turner, Conglomerate Mergers and Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 78 Harv.L.Rev. 1313, 1363 (1965). A careful search of the record discloses no evidence that firms in the residential market recognized Stanley as a likely entrant.10 On the contrary, the record indicates that Stanley's position on the edge of the residential market had no competitive effect on those in the market. This is in dramatic contrast to potential competition cases in which the doctrine has been applied. See, e. g., United States v. El Paso Natural Gas Co., 376 U.S. 651, 659, 84 S.Ct. 1044, 12 L.Ed.2d 12 (1960); FTC v. Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.S. 568, 87 S.Ct. 1224, 18 L.Ed.2d 303 (1967).11 Thus, another peg upon which the Commission relies must fall.

86

The Commission's conclusion that the instant merger raised barriers to entry is likewise not supported by substantial evidence. The Commission found three barriers to entry: (1) the cost of the initial investment in die-casting equipment and design which would be required (approximately $600,000); (2) the need for a full line of up-to-date product styles; and (3) the cost of sales promotion and advertising in trade journals. At the same time the Commission rejected the Hearing Examiner's reliance as a factor on the difficulty of securing channels of distribution.

87

There is no direct or circumstantial evidence in the record that the $600,000 initial start-up costs, $400,000 of which might be needed to acquire machinery, would be increased by the Stanley-Amerock merger. Nor is there any substantial evidentiary support for the conclusion that the need for product differentiation might be increased. Stanley was not a style oriented company; its history was grounded in the production of non-ornamental hardware and tools. Finally, there is no substantial evidence to support the conclusion that the merger would increase the need for sales promotion and advertising. The Commission conceded that "advertising at the consumer level may be small" but rlied on the cost of advertisements in trade publications-somewhere in the vicinity of $50,000-$100,000. These figures are a far cry from the $80,000,000 per year found to be a decisive element in the landmark case of FTC v. Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.S. 568, 87 S.Ct. 1224, 18 L.Ed.2d 303 (1967); see also General Foods Corp. v. FTC, 386 F.2d 936 (3d Cir. 1967), cert. denied, 391 U.S. 919, 88 S.Ct. 1805, 20 L.Ed.2d 657 (1968). Furthermore, the Commission fails to point to any evidence indicating that the instant merger would increase an entrant's need for, or cost of, advertising. What is crucial is that unlike Procter & Gamble and General Foods, which dealt with consumer items where massive advertising was the crucial competitive factor, the role of advertising and sales promotion here is of minor significance and hence does not pose a barrier to entry.

88

The concept that a merger may operate to raise barriers of entry is based upon the assumption that price levels and profit margins in the industry would, but for the merger, be sufficiently high to overcome the cost of entry and thus attract new entrants. Here that is not the case. Prices were low, profits were modest at best, and there is no evidence that ease of entry, which existed before the merger, was in any way affected by it.

89

In support of its conclusion that the merger eliminated Stanley's potential competition, the Commission advanced for the first time a new theory, namely, that but for the merger Stanley might have entered the residential market by a so-called "toe-hold" acquisition, which here means that it might have acquired control over one of the smaller, nondominant firms in the cabinet hardware market instead of merging with Amerock. This theory was neither suggested in the complaint nor advanced in the hearings before the Examiner. Nor was any mention of it made by the Hearing Examiner. Indeed it was not suggested, either by the Commission or any other body, until a year after the record in the case had been closed and three months after the parties had submitted their briefs to the Commission. Then for the first time, the idea was advanced by the Commission in Bendix Corp. v. FTC (FTC Dkt. No. 8739), 3 Trade Reg. Rep. p 19,288 (June 18, 1970), which was reversed by the Sixth Circuit on the ground that "Bendix had no notice that it was charged under the toe-hold theory . . . and . . no opportunity to present evidence in defense against this theory." Bendix Corp. v. FTC, 450 F.2d 534, 537 (6th Cir. 1971).

90

Since Stanley was never given timely notice of the toe-hold theory or an opportunity to be heard and to introduce evidence with respect to it, I concur in Judge Kaufman's view12 that the Commission was precluded from basing its decision on that ground. See Bendix Corporation v. FTC, 450 F.2d 534 (6th Cir. 1971); cf. Rodale Press, Inc. v. FTC, 132 U.S.App.D.C. 317, 407 F.2d 1252 (1968). To countenance such a procedure would be to deny Stanley the due process that is mandated by the Fifth Amendment and by Sec. 5 of the Administrative Procedure Act.13

91

In any event the Commission's newly espoused post-hearing "toe-hold" theory is not supported by substantial evidence. The record is clear that the June 10, 1964 recommendation of subordinate Hardware Division personnel that Ajax or Jaybee be acquired was rejected later that month by the Department Managers of that Division, who recommended to D. W. Davis, Executive Vice President, that no such acquisition be made. This recommendation was accepted and approved by the company's management.

Conclusion

92

Vigorous enforcement of antitrust laws to bar mergers that may substantially lessen competition is essential to the economic lifeblood of this nation. But Congress has not outlawed all mergers. Nor has it, despite recommendations of some distinguished experts in the field, prescribed arbitrary standards for illegality which would prohibit every merger falling within a precise definition, even those in which the market percentage of one of the parties may be de minimis. On the contrary, Congress has recognized that antitrust flexibility is essential, since not all mergers threaten harm to the public, some even have the effect of promoting competition, and the issues turn on an understanding of the complexities of any given market.

93

The Commission assumes the burden of proving that any merger attacked by it will have the probable effect of substantially lessening competition or tending to create a monopoly. This it has failed to do in the present case. After a Hearing Examiner erred in denying Stanley the right to cross-examine those witnesses relied upon by him as the basis of his decision, the Commission, rather than remand for cross-examination, sought to sustain his decision upon a different evidentiary basis. Apparently recognizing the weakness of the grounds chosen by the Commission, the Court has affirmed on still different grounds. In view of the undisputed evidence as to the extremely limited actual competitive overlap, the vigorous competition in the marketplace, the absence of any trend toward concentration and the small percentage of the market controlled by Stanley (whether it be labelled .35% or 1%), the effect is automatically to hold such a merger illegal, thus in substance declaring it to be a per se violation because of the percentages involved.

94

Since the Commission's decision is not supported by substantial evidence, I would reverse.

1

15 U.S.C. Sec. 18. Section 7 as amended, provides:

"No corporation engaged in commerce shall acquire, directly or indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share capital and no corporation subject to the jurisdiction of the Federal Trade Commission shall acquire the whole or any part of the assets of another corporation engaged also in commerce, where in any line of commerce in any section of the country, the effect of such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a monopoly."

2

15 U.S.C. Sec. 45(a)(1). That section provides:

"Unfair methods of competition in commerce, and unfair or deceptive acts or practices in commerce, are declared unlawful."

The complaint in this case, issued against Stanley on April 30, 1968, charged a violation of Clayton Sec. 7 and Federal Trade Commission Act, Sec. 5. The Commission found that the merger transgressed both statutes. Although a violation of Sec. 5 is not necessarily a violation of Sec. 7, see Federal Trade Commission v. Sperry Hutchinson, 405 U.S. 233, 246, 92 S.Ct. 898, 31 L.Ed.2d 170 (1972), it is the case that every violation of Sec. 7 is also a violation of Sec. 5. Since we hold that the Stanley-Amerock merger is illegal under Sec. 7, and therefore illegal under Sec. 5, we need not give special consideration to Sec. 5 analysis.

3

The Commission's decision was rendered on May 17, 1971

4

For our discussion of the relevant product market see p. 500

5

We stress that neither of these lines constitutes a separate product market for purposes of this case, an element ignored in the dissenting opinion. Our division of the market at this point is designed to serve descriptive, not analytic, purposes

6

The respective totals in cabinet hardware sales, and Stanley's and Amerock's percentage market shares, were agreed to by stipulation

7

                                                       1965
                                     Cabinet Hardware Sales in U.
                                            S.Total Assets
1.  Amerock Corp....................................... $18,218,474   25,133,914
2.  National Lock Company ............................. $11,499,445   37,992,215
3.  Ajax Hardware Corp.................................. $6,798,000    3,338,412
4.  Knape & Vogt Mfg. Co................................ $6,013,304    7,968,450
5.  Jaybee Mfg. Corp.................................... $3,056,673    1,710,989
6.  Grant Pulley & Hardware Corp........................ $2,168,397    2,369,165
7.  David Allison Co., Inc.............................. $1,500,000    1,500,000
8.  Tassell Industries, Inc............................. $1,408,600    2,483,424
9.  Hyer Hardware Mfg. Corp............................. $1,344,464      524,452
10.  Stanley Hardware Division ........................... $814,000  125,926,000
8

Stanley's position is that the Commission's potential competition theory is inadequate to support a finding of merger illegality in this case. The Commission held that Stanley was a reasonably probable entrant into the residential cabinet hardware market, and that Stanley would have entered by internal development had it not acquired Amerock. In the Commission's view, the merger eliminated Stanley as a potential entrant, removed the "disciplining effect" it exercised on the market, and raised barriers to entry in an already concentrated market. The Commission did not find that Stanley was the "most likely entrant," see FTC v. Procter & Gamble, 386 U.S. 568, 581, 87 S.Ct. 1224, 18 L.Ed.2d 303 (1967); cf. United States v. El Paso Natural Gas, 376 U.S. 651, 658-659, 84 S.Ct. 1044, 12 L.Ed.2d 12 (1964). In addition, the Commission did not point to any evidence indicating that Stanley exercised a "disciplining effect" on the market, nor did it illustrate how Stanley's acquisition of Amerock would contribute to raising barriers to entry in the residential cabinet hardware industry. Inasmuch as we conclude that the Stanley-Amerock merger is illegal because it eliminated substantial actual competition and thereby may lessen competition in the cabinet market as a whole, we need not decide the merits of the potential competition case

Thus, in this part of our opinion, we consider Stanley's argument that the actual competition theory was not "adequately disclosed". In Part III, we shall treat the question whether that ground is "adequately sustained" by substantial evidence.

9

Thus, to note only a few examples, at page 23 of its brief Stanley argued that "[t]he so-called 'horizontal' aspects of the case, i. e., the amount of actual competition in cabinet hardware eliminated by the merger, is de minimis, and the Examiner erred in not so finding." At pages 25-26 of its brief, Stanley argued that the examiner had incorrectly assessed "the amount of actual competition in fact eliminated by the merger." And finally Stanley asserted that "[i]n view of all the considerations summarized above [at pages 23-30 of its brief], it is clear that the horizontal aspect of this case is quite different from the situations involved in the leading horizontal cases . . . ."

10

K. Kaysen & D. Turner, Antitrust Policy: An Economic and Legal Analysis 72 (1959), and J. Bain, Industrial Organization 14-41 (2d ed. 1968)

11

K. Kaysen & D. Turner, supra, at 133; Stigler, Mergers and Preventive Antitrust, 114 U.Pa.L.Rev. 176, 182 (1955)

12

Our dissenting brother ignores this admonition, and would confine the power of antitrust enforcement agencies to cases where a "trend" toward concentration in the industry has been proven. In doing so, he disregards the teaching of Continental Can that actual concentration is a far more insidious base upon which to build a merger. This would seem to pay greater heed to the symptom than the disease

13

Stanley insists that such a market is not "concentrated." They cite Justice Department Merger Guidelines, see 1 Trade Reg. Law Rep. p 4510, which indicate that a market is highly concentrated when shares of the four largest firms account for 75% or more of the market. But as often proves true, reading on to the end of a sentence can be instructive. It appears that the Department of Justice will ordinarily challenge mergers in a "highly concentrated market" where the acquired and acquiring firm account for 1% and 15% of the market respectively, 1 Trade Reg. Law Rep. p 4510 at 6884. But the Department also characterizes some markets as "less highly concentrated"-markets in which the four leading firms account for less than 75% of the market. Under such conditions the Department will ordinarily challenge mergers when the parties account for 1% and 25% of the market. Stanley controlled 1% of the cabinet hardware market; Amerock 22-24%. It should be evident that market shares in this case are sufficiently close to the Department guidelines to cause us to hesitate before accepting Stanley's view

14

Although the teachings of scholars cannot be dispositive, it would be foolhardy, in an area as complicated as this, to wholly disregard the lessons they have learned in a lifetime of study

15

Kaysen & Turner, supra, at 72. The authors define economic markets in terms of four levels of concentration. A "dominant firm" or "partial monopoly" market is one in which a single large firm supplies 60% of the market and no other seller supplies a significant portion of the demand. "Tight oligopoly" is the next level of concentration. See also Bain, Industrial Organization 131 (2d ed. 1968). (Market in which four firms control 50% reflects high-moderate concentration.)

16

Stanley's own partial reliance on Justice Department Merger guidelines, discussed at note 13, supra, reflects this same view. Stanley concedes that the Justice Department's view expressed in its guidelines should be given special weight; so too, we believe, should the Commission's views

17

United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, supra, 374 U.S. at 362, 83 S.Ct. at 1741

18

The relevant geographic markets in Pabst were Wisconsin, the Tri-State market consisting of Wisconsin, Michigan and Illinois, and the Nation. The Court held that "the evidence as to the probable effect of the merger on competition in Wisconsin, in the three-state area, and in the entire country was sufficient to show a violation of Sec. 7 in each and all of these three areas." 384 U.S., at 552, 86 S.Ct., at 1669

19

The Court found that Alcoa's acquisition of Rome Cable Corporation was reasonably likely to result in a substantial lessening of competition in the highly, concentrated aluminum conductor industry where 5 companies controlled 76% of the relevant market. Alcoa was the leading producer of aluminum conductor, with 27.8% of the market; Rome was ninth with 1.3%

20

United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, supra, 377 U.S. at 281, 84 S.Ct. 1283

21

Stanley relies on Tampa Electric Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 365 U.S. 320, 81 S.Ct. 623, 5 L.Ed.2d 580 (1961) to support its assertion that 1% is a de minimis share of the market. Tampa was brought under Sec. 3 of the Clayton Act, which forbids certain types of exclusive dealing contracts where the effect of such a contract may be substantially to lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly in any line of commerce. 15 U.S.C. Sec. 14. Tampa and Nashville had entered into a requirements contract under which Nashville agreed to supply Tampa's coal requirements for a period of twenty years. The District Court and the Court of Appeals held the contract invalid under Sec. 3, and the Supreme Court reversed. The Court said: ". . . the proportionate volume of the total relevant coal product as to which the challenged contract preempted competition, less than 1%, is, conservatively speaking, quite insubstantial. A more accurate figure, even assuming pre-emption to the extent of the maximum anticipated total requirements . . . would be .77%." 365 U.S., at 333, 81 S.Ct., at 631. Justices Black and Douglas dissented

"Stanley and our dissenting brother," ignore the significance of the fact that Tampa Electric involved the validity of a contract under Clayton Sec. 3, not Sec. 7. The parameters of analysis in Sec. 7 cases are not the same as in Sec. 3 cases. Courts are cautioned to exercise greater care before upholding a merger under Sec. 7 inasmuch as "integration by merger is more suspect than integration by contract, because of the greater permanence of the former." United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, supra, 374 U.S., at 366, 83 S.Ct., at 1743. Furthermore, the Court in Tampa thought it necessary to distinguish Standard Fashion Company v. Magrane-Houston Company, 258 U.S. 346, 42 S.Ct. 360, 66 L.Ed. 653 (1922), a prior Sec. 3 case which had invalidated a two-year exclusive agency contract between Standard, a manufacturer and distributor of patterns, and Margane, a Boston retail dry goods store. Standard Fashions, the Court said, involved a market with a dominant seller and there was no evidence of any concentration in the Tampa product market. Because the instant case calls into question the validity of a merger under Sec. 7, not the legality of a contract under Sec. 3, and because of the concentrated structure of the cabinet hardware market, we find Stanley's reliance on Tampa Electric misplaced.

Stanley has also cited to us, without discussion, several district court cases, which, it says, involved de minimis foreclosures. We have carefully considered these cases and find them inapposite.

22

In fact, some scholars are of the view that any horizontal acquisition involving a firm with more than 20% of the relevant market-Amerock's share is 22--24%-should be prima facie illegal. See K. Kaysen & D. Turner, supra, at 133. Stigler, Mergers and Preventive Antitrust, 104 U.Pa.L.Rev. 176, 182 (1955)

23

The Commission found that it was reasonably probable that Stanley would have become increasingly more active in the residential cabinet hardware segment of the relevant market by way of internal expansion had expansion not been effected by merger. Stanley disputes this finding and says that top level Stanley management rejectd the option of internal expansion in residential cabinet hardware. Instead, however, Stanley concedes that in January, 1965, approximately nine months prior to initial merger contacts between Stanley and Amerock, it was decided that Stanley would expand its production of architectural cabinet hardware. Donald Davis, then Executive Vice-President and now President of Stanley, in testimony before the Trial Examiner, stated: "I was convinced that the best thing for the Hardware Division to do was to try to maximize their sales and profits in their existing product lines rather than spending their time and efforts looking for . . . new growth areas . . ." And he asserted that Stanley had decided "to concentrate [its] efforts in the area where [it] had some strength, namely, architectural cabinet hardware . . . ."

Whether we accept the Commission's or Stanley's view, once it is understood that the parties agreed that the cabinet hardware market as a whole is the relevant product market for this case, it is clear that Stanley had plans to become an even more significant competitor in the market. Therefore maintenance of its independence in the concentrated market, even as a 1% competitor, was of great importance in holding open the possibility of future deconcentration.

24

In view of our decision in this case, we have no occasion to pass on the merits of the Commission's "toe-hold theory" which would have declared this merger illegal for the reason that even if Stanley were permitted to expand in the market via acquisition, it should have purchased one of the lesser firms in the industry, and not the market leader. Stanley urges that the "toehold theory" was not raised in the complaint, never litigated at the hearing, nor considered by the Examiner. It contends therefore, that any judgment based on the "toehold theory" would be violative of Fifth Amendment Due Process, and Section 5 of the Administrative Procedure Act, 5 U.S.C. Sec. 554. We agree that the "toehold theory" was not litigated before the Examiner, and that the Commission was without authority to consider it. Cf. Bendix Corp. v. FTC, 450 F.2d 534 (6th Cir. 1971). Because the "toehold theory," however, was an alternative basis of illegality, and since the actual competition case adequately established the finding of invalidity under the Clayton Act by substantial evidence, the Commission's error worked no prejudice to Stanley

Finally, Stanley contends that the Commission prejudged the facts of the case thereby denying petitioner its right to a fair hearing. We have given this charge the serious attention it deserves but find it to be without merit.

1

The Hearing Examiner concluded:

"The acquisition and merger of Amerock the leading independent domestic manufacturer and seller by Stanley increased this high level of concentration and may result in a substantial lessening of competition in the said cabinet hardware market because of the elimination of Stanley as a reasonably probable, potentially capable and significant domestic manufacturer and seller in the residential cabinet hardware segment of the said market, and particularly in the decorative residential cabinet hardware sales area of the said market."

2

The Commission described the Hearing Examiner's Initial Decision as follows:

"Thus, the examiner found that respondent's acquisition of Amerock lessened competition because (1) absent the merger Stanley would probably have entered the cabinet hardware market on its own; (2) the elimination of Stanley as a potential competitor had the effect of increasing the barriers to entry; and (3) Stanley, as a potential competitor, had an influence on the performance of the cabinet hardware market.

"On the basis of these findings, the hearing examiner concluded that the effect of the merger may be to substantially lessen competition in the cabinet hardware market in violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act and Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act."

3

United States v. Pabst Brewing Co., 384 U.S. 546, 86 S.Ct. 1665, 16 L.Ed.2d 765 (1966); United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 377 U.S. 271, 84 S.Ct. 1283, 12 L.Ed.2d 314 (1964); United States v. Continental Can Co., 378 U.S. 441, 84 S. Ct. 1738, 12 L.Ed.2d 953 (1964); Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 8 L.Ed.2d 510 (1962); United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 83 S.Ct. 1715, 10 L. Ed.2d 915 (1963)

4

Stanley's $600,000 sales constituted 7 1/2% of all institutional cabinet hardware sales; Amerock's $200,00 equalled about 2 1/2%

5

The $84,000 overlap is based on the fact that Stanley's sales through Architectural OEM's was only $44,000 (compared with Amerock's sales of $160,000) and Amerock's sales of institutional hardware to Contracts Hardware Distributors only $40,000 (compared with Stanley's sales of $570,000)

6

E. g., United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, supra; United States v. Von's Grocery Co., 384 U.S. 270, 86 S.Ct. 1478, 16 L.Ed.2d 555 (1966); United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, supra; Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, supra; United States v. Continental Can Co., supra; United States v. Pabst Brewing Co., supra

7

Based upon figures published in the trade magazine Kitchen Week

8

National Lock, Tassell, Faultless and Bossick-Sack, for example, are respectively subsidiaries of Keystone Consolidated Industries, Gulf & Western Industries, Bliss & Laughlin Industries, and Stewart-Warner Corporation. In addition Yale & Towne, Embart Corp., and Eaton Corp., all large companies produce their own lines of cabinet hardware either directly or through subsidiaries

9

See footnotes 8 and 23 (supra) of the majority opinion. Footnote 8 rejects the Commission's contention that it proved that Stanley was the most likely potential entrant, that it served to discipline the market and that the merger raised barriers to entry. Footnote 23 similarly disparages the Commission's toe-hold theory

10

Compare footnote 8 of the majority opinion, which reaches substantially the same conclusion. The Examiner made no finding that Stanley, as a potential competitor at the market's edge, had any competitive effect upon the those in the market, and witnesses representing competitors in the cabinet hardware market testified that it did not have such an influence

11

It may well be, as the majority opinion suggests, that FTC v. Procter & Gamble, 386 U.S. 568, 87 S.Ct. 1224, 18 L.Ed.2d 303 (1967), requires a finding that the acquiring firm was "the most likely entrant." Id. at 581, 87 S.Ct. 1224. Since we conclude that under any standard there is no substantial evidence to indicate that Stanley exercised a disciplining effect, that issue is not reached. Similarly, we need not discuss the significance of other potential entrants on the market

12

Compare footnote 23 of the majority opinion

13

Section 5 of the APA provides in relevant part:

"Persons entitled to notice of an agency hearing shall be timely informed of . . . (3) the matters of fact and law asserted." 5 U.S.C. Sec. 554.